A View on Affordable Housing

Last month the head of a Washington D.C.-based affordable housing organization asked me to attend a meeting in the Hart Senate Office Building to give my views on “Corker-Warner 2.0” and its potential effect on low- and moderate-income mortgage borrowers. As I presented my perspective and arguments, a Senator with whom I had not met before seemed interested in and intrigued by them, and asked me if I could write them up. I did, and sent the resulting paper to the Senator’s staff. Since affordable housing has been a key sticking point for reform legislation in Congress, I thought readers of this blog would be interested in the text of the paper, which I’ve reproduced below.

*                                                                  *                                                                    *

The need for reform

For the past several decades the U.S. has had two general sources of financing for conventional (i.e., non-government guaranteed) home mortgages: depository institutions and the international capital markets. Depository institutions finance home mortgages using consumer deposits and purchased funds; capital markets investors finance them by purchasing mortgage-backed securities (or MBS).

In the mid-1970s three-quarters of all home mortgages were made and held by depositories, mainly thrift institutions. Two successive thrift crises—the first in the late 1970s triggered by deposit deregulation and the second in the late 1980s triggered by asset deregulation—caused that system to collapse. Thrifts’ share of home mortgages financed plunged from 57 percent in 1975 to just 17 percent in 1995. Financing by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, sourced from the international capital markets, filled almost the entire gap. At the end of the 1990s, Fannie and Freddie either owned or guaranteed more than 40 percent of all home mortgages, up from less than 5 percent 25 years earlier.

In the early 2000s, during a time when the Federal Reserve and Treasury were embracing free market principles and declining to regulate new lending practices or mechanisms, private-label securities (PLS) emerged as an alternative to mortgage securitization by Fannie and Freddie. PLS placed few limits on the riskiness of the loans they would accept, and as a consequence issuance of PLS increased rapidly. In 2004, more new mortgages were being financed by PLS than by Fannie, Freddie and Ginnie Mae MBS combined. Easy, ample and low-cost borrower access to mortgages through unregulated PLS issuance fueled an unsustainable housing boom that continued until the fall of 2007, when the PLS market finally collapsed amidst an avalanche of delinquencies and defaults.

We now have nearly ten years’ worth of performance data on mortgages financed just prior to the crisis by PLS, FDIC-insured depository institutions, and Fannie and Freddie. These data leave no doubt as to where the flaws in the mortgage finance system were. Cumulative loss rates on the PLS that were outstanding at the end of 2007 exceed 25 percent, and loss rates on home loans made and held by depository institutions as of the same date exceed 12 percent. In contrast, loss rates on year-end 2007 loans held or guaranteed by Fannie and Freddie barely exceed 4 percent.

Capital markets investors and Congress understood what had happened in the PLS market—where an absence of regulation allowed both primary market lenders and Wall Street securities issuers with no capital at risk to make money off mortgages that had little chance of being repaid—and they reacted accordingly. Congress responded with the 2010 Dodd-Frank Act, which required lenders to apply an “ability to repay” rule to mortgage borrowers and, through the “qualified mortgage” (QM) standard, effectively prohibited the most risky mortgage products and loan features that proliferated during the PLS bubble. Investors simply abandoned the PLS market due to its inherent conflicts of interest, and they have not come back

From 2004 through 2006, the PLS market had been financing nearly two of every five new home mortgages in the country. When it suddenly imploded, that left the commercial banks, Fannie and Freddie, and the FHA to pick up the slack. All were under stress because of the overheated housing market, calling into question how, and even whether, the mortgage market could continue to function.

What happened at this point is disputed, but compelling evidence supports the notion that Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson made a policy decision to use what he termed “the awesome power of the government” to force Fannie and Freddie into conservatorship—without statutory authority, against their will, and while they remained in compliance with their regulatory capital requirements—because, as he told the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, “[Fannie and Freddie] were the only game in town,” and with mortgage credit drying up, they “more than anyone, were the engine we needed to get through the problem.”

At the same time, Treasury seems to have found in the turmoil of the financial crisis a unique opportunity to strengthen the competitive position in the $10 trillion home mortgage market of the commercial banks it regulates, at the expense of Fannie and Freddie and the capital markets investors to whom they sell their securities.

As soon as the companies were put in conservatorship, Treasury required them to shrink their combined $1.6 trillion mortgage portfolios by 10 percent per year (later increased to 15 percent per year), even though the spread income from those portfolios helped offset their credit losses. Shortly afterwards, Treasury and the companies’ conservator, the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), used highly pessimistic estimates of future losses to justify recording $320 billion in non-cash expenses that exhausted the companies’ capital and caused them to draw $187 billion in senior preferred stock they did not need and were not allowed to repay. Then, just as the artificial losses that caused this alleged “bailout” were about to reverse (as they did, in only 18 months), Treasury and FHFA agreed to a “net worth sweep” that required Fannie and Freddie to pay all of their net income to Treasury in perpetuity, ensuring that they would remain in conservatorship until Treasury and advocates for the banking industry could come up with a plan to replace them.

Affordable housing borrowers are critically dependent on a low-cost and efficiently functioning secondary market. Prior to the 2008 financial crisis, Fannie and Freddie had been able to support these borrowers by using cross-subsidization to price their credit guarantees more advantageously, and by purchasing nonstandard affordable housing loans for portfolio. Today, Fannie and Freddie’s portfolios are less than one- third their former size—because of Treasury’s directive to shrink them—and they operate with guaranty fees set artificially high by their conservator, FHFA, not based on the riskiness of the loans they guarantee but instead, in the words of the agency, to “reduce their market share,” and “encourage more private sector participation.”

Since the mid-1990s more funding for mortgages has been provided by capital markets investors than by depository institutions, so primary market lenders use the cost of selling into the secondary market to determine their quoted mortgage rates. Increases in the cost of the credit guaranty process, i.e., MBS guaranty fees, therefore get passed on to all borrowers, whether their loans are sold or not.

Dodd-Frank reformed both the PLS market and primary market mortgage lenders through the QM standard and the ability-to-repay rule, and regulators have raised banks’ capital requirements. Only Fannie and Freddie remain unreformed, because advocates for the banking industry insist not on reform that benefits the financial system and homebuyers but on reform that benefits the competitive position of primary market lenders. With the PLS market dormant, Fannie and Freddie are virtually the sole means of tapping the capital markets for money to finance conventional mortgages. Holding this financing channel hostage to banks’ demands that it be restructured in a way that makes it more costly and less efficient—for the patently false reason that its current structure is a “failed business model” that caused the financial crisis—has had severe negative consequences for the mortgage system as a whole, and for affordable housing borrowers in particular. Congress and Treasury are the only entities that can remedy this situation. 

Support for affordable housing

 The government can increase the availability and lower the cost of mortgages for affordable housing in three ways: (a) fostering the development of a secondary market system that provides the lowest-cost mortgages to the widest range of borrower types, consistent with an agreed-upon standard of taxpayer protection; (b) setting mandatory affordable housing goals, and (c) devising and implementing subsidy programs that assist underserved populations. Taking each in turn:

A credit guaranty mechanism that expands borrower access

Advocates for commercial banks have sought legislative replacements for Fannie and Freddie for nearly a decade. Their idea in the 2013 Corker-Warner bill was a cumbersome bureaucracy called the Federal Mortgage Insurance Corporation; today the new version of Corker-Warner calls for multiple credit guarantors with explicit government guarantees on the securities they issue. Both versions, however, offer self-serving solutions to invented problems, and fail because Fannie and Freddie’s business model, with its proven track record of providing efficient and low-cost access to capital markets funding, works far better than the proposed alternatives.

Yet as the 2008 financial crisis revealed, there are weaknesses in this model that can and should be remedied. The companies need a new and more effective capital standard; they need better (and less adversarial) regulation, and they perhaps also should have utility-like limits on their returns, as a risk-control measure. These reforms can be done either in legislation or administratively. Whichever course is followed, however, the most critical aspect of Fannie and Freddie reform for access and affordability will be the capital standard.

The capital standard imposed upon Fannie and Freddie, or any credit guarantor, must strike a careful and deliberate balance between a very high level of taxpayer protection on the one hand and the cost and breadth of access to mortgages on the other. Too little capital will expose the taxpayer to potential losses; too much capital, or a standard that does not tie capital to credit risk, will distort guaranty fee pricing and impede the flow of capital market funds into mortgages, for affordable housing borrowers in particular.

Fortunately, Congress already has addressed the issue of credit guarantor capital, and come up with the right answer. Section 1110 of the Housing and Economic Recovery Act (HERA) of 2008 states, “The Director [of FHFA] shall, by regulation, establish risk-based capital requirements for the enterprises to ensure that the enterprises operate in a safe and sound manner, maintaining sufficient capital and reserves to support the risks that arise in the operations and management of the enterprises.” A true risk-based capital standard for Fannie and Freddie, consistent with HERA, will result in the least amount of unnecessary capital, the lowest average guaranty fees, and the greatest flexibility to use cross-subsidization to support the affordable housing community, while still providing an extremely high level of taxpayer protection.

FHFA has not yet implemented the capital provision in HERA, likely because it and Treasury have chosen to manage Fannie and Freddie in conservatorship in a manner consistent with ultimately winding them down and replacing them. That is a serious policy mistake that needs to be corrected by Congress, or by Treasury itself.

To implement the risk-based standard in HERA, Congress or Treasury first would pick the stress environment it wants the guarantors to be able to protect against. (The 25 percent nationwide decline in home prices used in the Dodd-Frank stress tests for banks would be a likely candidate). FHFA then would use Fannie and Freddie’s historical data to project default rates and loss severities during this environment, by risk category—at a minimum, combinations of loan-to-value ratios and credit scores—and the resulting stress loss amounts would be the basis for setting the companies’ new capital requirements, at the risk-category level.

Fannie and Freddie’s experience during and after the 2008 financial crisis suggests how they would have to capitalize against a future 25 percent home price decline. With their loans and MBS at the end of 2007, and the (low) guaranty fees they then were charging, 2 percent capital would have been more than enough to absorb all of the credit losses on those books of business. FHFA of course will set the actual stress capital levels. It also should impose a minimum capital ratio, which will benefit affordable housing borrowers by making it impossible for Fannie or Freddie to drive their required capital below that minimum by unduly favoring pristine credits.

A true risk-based capital standard for Fannie and Freddie, endorsed by Treasury as meeting a rigorous stress standard for taxpayer protection, would obviate the need for an explicit government guaranty on their mortgage-backed securities. Moreover, if catastrophic loss insurance were necessary to enhance Fannie and Freddie’s credit quality (to hold down their MBS yields), private insurers could provide it; with true risk-based capital, insurers would know the precise thresholds, by risk category, at which their loss coverage would kick in, and could price for it accordingly.

Mandatory affordable housing goals

The potential impact of mandatory affordable housing goals for Fannie and Freddie, or any credit guarantor, is limited by the fact that these companies do not originate mortgages; they only can guarantee the loans primary market lenders make. Even so, housing goals can be used to create incentives for secondary market companies to channel the benefits of capital markets financing to subcategories of underserved borrower. A regulator should have the authority to impose penalties on a credit guarantor if, in any year, its percentage of affordable housing business—either overall or in an underserved subcategory designated by Congress—falls short of the percentage originated in the primary market that year.

Housing goals also can be used to promote cooperative initiatives with state and local governments, nonprofit institutions and community housing groups to create custom-tailored products for targeted housing needs on a smaller scale, although for this to be effective a credit guarantor will need to be able to hold some number of these loans on its balance sheet, since many will not be eligible for securitization.

HERA contains a robust set of housing goals for Fannie and Freddie, which would be maintained in administrative reform of the companies. Mandatory credit guarantor housing goals may be more difficult to include in new legislation, given the political disagreements over their appropriate role.

Subsidy programs that support underserved populations

The bank-promoted bill currently being drafted in the Senate Banking Committee relies almost exclusively on direct subsidy programs to assist affordable housing borrowers, funding these programs with a ten basis point Mortgage Access Fee.

Supporters of this mechanism are correct that direct subsidy programs are more efficient, on a dollar-for-dollar basis, than the cross-subsidies historically done in the secondary market through charging lower-risk borrowers higher guaranty fees so that guaranty fees for higher-risk borrowers can be reduced. But the draft Senate bill errs in presenting direct subsidies as an alternative to cross-subsidies, rather than as a complement to them. The two are independent; direct subsidy programs do not in any way lessen the importance of doing as much as possible to support affordable housing through an efficient credit guaranty mechanism.

The draft Senate bill also proposes to assess the Mortgage Access Fee only on loans that have secondary market credit guarantees. This creates two problems, both of which can be fixed by assessing the fee on all new mortgages. The first is transmittal leakage. Because a credit guarantor’s ten basis point Mortgage Access Fee will be added to its guaranty fee, the same amount also will be added to the mortgage rates quoted by primary market lenders, for the reason noted earlier. But these ten basis points paid by the borrower only will enter the affordable housing subsidy pool if the loan receives a credit guaranty; a lender that keeps a loan in portfolio also keeps the borrower’s ten basis points. A Mortgage Access Fee on all new mortgages will avoid this leakage (and windfall for primary market portfolio lenders), and ensure that all monies collected from the fee go to their intended beneficiaries.

The second problem with a Mortgage Access Fee charged only on loans financed in the secondary market is that it unnecessarily ties the subsidy programs that benefit from such a fee to legislative mortgage reform, which will be challenging to enact. A Mortgage Access Fee on all new mortgages would be less controversial as a stand-alone measure, and thus more likely to be implemented.

*                                                                  *                                                                *

How best to address the needs of the affordable housing community in mortgage reform is no mystery. But that hasn’t been the goal of secondary mortgage market reformers—it’s dominance of the $10 trillion residential mortgage market by large primary market banks. With Fannie and Freddie banned from political activities, these banks have been free to distort the record, define the objectives of secondary market reform, and put forth reform proposals that benefit themselves. Advocates for affordable housing, as well as community banks, realize this, and are responding with fact-based rebuttals and alternatives of their own. That’s a very good thing. If large primary market lenders are allowed to dictate how the capital markets-based financing channel is structured and operates, homebuyers in general, and affordable housing borrowers in particular, will pay a steep price in both cost and access.

157 thoughts on “A View on Affordable Housing

  1. the hindes/jacobs appeal in 3rd circuit has been “calendared” for 9/5/18. this means that a merits panel will have been assigned to this case and will have had at least 4 weeks prior thereto to read briefs and prepare. if one of the three judges of the merits panel desires oral argument then that will be scheduled, presumably in early September as well. we do not know yet which judges will comprise the panel.

    I agree with Tim that hindes/jacobs presents then strongest claim that the NWS is beyond the authority of fhfa as conservator (which is not to say that the conserve/preserve argument was not strong, in my view). so assuming that oral argument is requested (which I would think is a safe bet), this will be an important argument to follow.

    rolg

    Liked by 1 person

    1. I found the fact that the Bhatti case decision came out 1(?) week after Lucia very interesting. Not so much that he didn’t “reconsider” after Lucia came down, but he did, realized it made a problem and wanted to get out of Dodge quickly. I was thinking that when it came down he quickly put out his decision so he wouldn’t have to get tangled into the can of worms opened by Lucia. Maybe I am wrong, but is it not curious he puts out his decision just a week after Lucia, the day after a holiday when people are thinking about other things? How long was he sitting on Bhatti? Then all the sudden – it seems – he puts out a decision. Was he working like mad on the 3rd, 4th? Probably not, unless he wanted to get it out. I think he knows the case has merits, but is punting. Now perhaps that is good, this probably will never be settled until the Supreme Court, and now the appeal can get started and we are that much closer in the long run.

      Like

    2. ROLG,
      I looked up the appeals process for the third circuit and it said that oral arguments are rarely granted . If one is not granted does the 9/5 date you gave mean that is the day the panel meets to discuss or do they decide that day? Thanks. As Tim indicated , this is the most straight forward case and if briefs are read before hand , a decision could be made on that date. It says the Third circuit doesn’t always issue written opinions but may just come out with a ruling.

      Like

      1. @jerry

        the calendar order was ambiguous as to the exact date of any oral argument, if indeed the panel wishes to hold it. I would think at least one of a three judge panel would want oral argument in this case, in which case there will be oral argument. even if there is no oral argument, the order said the merits panel may meet on another day during that first week of September. if there is no oral argument and the case is not rescheduled, then 9/5 would be the day for the panel to decide the case among themselves and allocate the opinion writing duties. this opinion would likely not be released until well after the first week of September. see http://www2.ca3.uscourts.gov/legacyfiles/2015_IOPs.pdf (see 5.5.3 as to timing).

        rolg

        Like

    3. (Judge) Kavanaugh’s net neutrality dissent also suggested he’s skeptical about the Supreme Court’s so-called Chevron doctrine, a 1984 precedent that said courts should tend to defer to federal agencies’ regulatory decisions when the agencies are interpreting ambiguous statutes. A move by conservative justices to overturn Chevron could lead to far tighter restrictions on federal regulatory powers.

      He opined and voted CFPB was unconstitutional.

      Like

  2. Good Morning
    May I ask a naïve question? What stops the government from exercising the warrants and keeping them forever ? If they cancel the senior preferred and start sharing the profits with shareholders (79.9/20.1) and paying dividends to junior preferred , would it not be a solution that may stop all the law suits and allow a quiet, long term, no hurry, healthy capitalization? Is it not a win-win-win solution? wins the government, wins the stakeholders, wins the people that need mortgages.
    So my question is whether there is a legal impediment for the government to own 79.9 of the GSEs?

    Like

    1. Canceling the senior preferred, allowing the companies to recapitalize, and having the government exercise the warrants (and then sell them, not “keep them forever”) are the primary elements of the Moelis plan. There is no legal impediment to the government doing that, but to date the administration has not decided that’s what it wants with Fannie and Freddie. I and many others believe it is the best solution for the financial system and homebuyers, but the large banks and Wall Street interests oppose it–they prefer a “bank-centric” secondary market, which will give them more control over and profitability from the residential mortgage market as a whole–so we remain at impasse, with Congress unable to decide what to do and the administration unwilling to. I continue to believe that the most likely catalyst for action on secondary mortgage reform will be a victory for the plaintiffs in one or more of the lawsuits.

      Liked by 5 people

      1. Re: Litigation as a catalyst, We have 3 interesting decisions coming up in the next 0-6 months with Bhatti, Saxton, and Collins. I say interesting because it seems the judges are open to the idea that the NWS was ultra-vires or there was a constitutional issue with FHFA. Curious how optimistic you are if at all with regards to the outcomes of these decisions?

        Like

        1. I don’t have much confidence in my ability to handicap these cases. I believe the plaintiffs have the facts and the law on their side on all of them, but in a regulatory case of this magnitude the government gets a lot of deference. I’m glad there are numerous cases under different theories of the laws; it improves our chances of winning one of them. I like the constitutional cases, because they have less judicial wiggle room. And I’m still holding out hope for the appeal in the Jacobs-Hindes case; that was my original favorite, and I haven’t given up on it.

          Like

      2. Tim – What do you think is the biggest reason behind the inaction from the current admin.? Simplistically, it seems they think that at this point, why not just wait it out until Corker/Hensarling are no longer in office. Thanks, curious to get your thoughts.

        Like

        1. Mnuchin knows that the current Congress is not going to act on Fannie and Freddie. At the end of April he said, “I just don’t think this is going to be a focus in this Congress. But we will come back to this next year, and this will be a big focus of mine post-the elections.” I hope that’s the case, but Mnuchin also said the administration would get mortgage reform done “reasonably fast” over a year and a half ago, and here we sit. The reality is that the status quo is quite comfortable for Treasury. Through FHFA, it controls Fannie and Freddie, and continues to sweep all their income into its coffers. It’s easy for Treasury to wait for some reason to initiate something (e.g., Congressional activity, or an adverse development in one of the court cases).

          Like

          1. @Martin

            again, another district court judge masquerading as j alfred prufrock.

            this will go up on appeal, but to paraphrase bellichik, it’s on to hindes/jacobs, Saxon and collins.

            rolg

            Liked by 1 person

          2. I’m obviously disappointed by this ruling, and had a couple of reactions to it–one specific and one general. My specific reaction is that, unlike the decision in the appeal of Perry Capital, which was based on contorted logic and deliberate misquoting of the HERA statute, Judge Schiltz’s ruling on whether plaintiffs had standing to bring the suit seemed to me to be reasonable. He said, “Plaintiffs have no coherent theory for how their injury—a Third Amendment that, in Plaintiff’s view, is unduly favorable to the President–could have resulted from the President having too little control over FHFA. Nor do plaintiffs have a coherent theory as to why giving the President more control of FHFA will lead to him renegotiating the Third Amendment so that it is less favorable to himself.” And while I’m not qualified to assess Judge Schiltz’s legal arguments in support of his statement that even absent the issue of standing he still would have ruled for defendants on the merits, I didn’t find those to be unreasonable either.

            My general (and bigger) concern relates to the first several pages of the decision, which show Judge Schiltz continuing the pattern of judges in the net worth sweep cases completely buying into the government’s argument that, to paraphrase, “Lending policies by government-sponsored companies Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac resulted in massive losses during the financial crisis; Treasury heroically saved them with an $187 billion bailout, and now greedy hedge funds want to recover the value of their investment by suing the government. They tried and failed to get the net worth sweep declared illegal as an APA violation, and now they’re trying to get the same result through this lawsuit.” (Judge Schiltz called this “killing the tree [to] kill one of its fruits).”

            It has now become clear that plaintiffs’ counsel in their initial filings in all of these cases did not react aggressively enough to the lies put out by Treasury and others about their handling of Fannie and Freddie during the crisis; those lies now have become embedded into the historical record, and plaintiffs are paying the price.

            The strategy by plaintiffs’ counsel not to attack the government’s actions or motives for the conservatorship in the initial filings (which it has changed in the more recent motions and amended complaints, but the damage has been done) was taken consciously, for what appeared at the time to be good reasons. Back then I had several conversations with plaintiffs’ counsel urging them to be more aggressive in challenging the government’s version of the 2008 takeovers. Their reason for not doing so went along the lines of: “it will be very difficult to win a challenge against the 2008 conservatorship decision because the courts grant great deference to regulators during a time of crisis, and if we call too much attention to the results of what FHFA and Treasury did to Fannie and Freddie after the conservatorship (i.e., running up their losses with non-cash expenses and forcing them to take so much senior preferred stock that they owed more each year in non-deductible senior preferred stock dividends than they ever had made in after-tax earnings), it will weaken the case we’re filing on behalf of the junior preferred holders, because the government’s argument then will be, ‘the net worth sweep really didn’t prejudice your clients, because the original terms of the PSPA would have made their shares worthless anyway’.” I understand how plaintiffs counsel could have thought that, but we’re now seeing how allowing the “false narrative” to become entrenched is backfiring.

            Framing plaintiffs’ cases as an opportunistic attempt to game the legal system for selfish financial advantage—as opposed to seeking a justified judicial remedy for the premeditated theft of all of the assets of two private companies who were operating in compliance with their capital standards at the time Treasury bullied them into conservatorship—gives any judge air cover to accept virtually all of the arguments made by the government in a motion to dismiss, and to grant that motion. Judge Schiltz showed early on that he would be no exception, when he essentially rejected the plaintiffs’ version of the facts in this statement: “Plaintiffs’ assertion that Fannie and Freddie could have remained solvent without the help of the federal government is dubious…but the Court is required to treat it as true at this stage of the litigation.”

            Liked by 1 person

          3. @Tim

            as always, spot on.

            it is interesting to note that in saxton oral arg, one judge asked fhfa counsel a question about what the judge said was Ps strongest argument, that fhfa director was under the direction of treasury in violation of HERA. this claim is the polar opposite of the unconstitutionally structured/fhfa independence argument, which judge schiltz notes suffers from a logical inconsistency…that if fhfa director was more subject to direction of POTUS, that would not have led to a NWS that was less advantageous to a POTUS controlled treasury.

            on other hand, having a fhfa director that was all too subject to treasury’s direction (notwithstanding not being subject to POTUS’s direction) would have been an argument judge schiltz would have seen more sympathetically from his logical point of view. but of course that is an argument pressed by Ps in saxton, not bhatti.

            but lastly, since when must a constitutional violation be premised upon whether its logic is manifest to a judge? if an agency is unconstitutionally structured, then it is unconstitutionally structured.

            rolg

            Liked by 1 person

          4. 1. Many judges use “moral” excuses to subconsciously cover their flaws in legal argument.

            2. Schiltz’s argument for 4+ year acting director is very weak. If he were right, no future senate confirmation of any cabinet staff is mandatary.

            Liked by 1 person

          5. Tim , I agree with you that plaintiffs counsel under estimated the,wrong but widely accepted, belief that the GSE were in desperately need of rescue at the time of the 2008 crisis. Also counsel under estimated the effect of the propaganda leitmotifs such as “failed business model” , ” taxpayer protection” , ” Fannie & Freddie caused the crisis”, “Greedy hedge funds” . You can delete a sentence from a computer at once, but it is very difficult to deleted an impression from a mind. The shareholders of FnF are victims of a propaganda scheme.

            Liked by 1 person

          6. Rolg,
            I am not surprised at Judge Schiltz ruling against plaintiffs for the unconstitutional structure based on his leaning in oral arguments. The big surprise and disappointment for me was the ruling on the appointments clause. It seemed like in oral arguments that he recognized that there was an issue with the appoints clause in this case but wasn’t comfortable with the remedy. With the Supreme Court ruling on the appointments clause I thought for sure that they gave him the remedy he was looking for and it was all but assured that he would rule for the plaintiffs. It feels like another case where someone “got to this judge. What justification does he make in his opinion that the appointments clause was not violated. Does he make a reasonable argument to you when someone is in office for almost 5 years without being approved by Congress?

            Liked by 1 person

          7. @jerry

            agree totally. it is as if he wrote his opinion before Lucia came down and was too “otherwise engaged” to reconsider. I don’t know how he can call the tenure length of an acting director without potus/senate confirmation to be nonjusticiable when SCOTUS held that a recess of 10 days was presumptively too short for a recess appointment…and clearly justiciable.

            rolg

            Liked by 1 person

    1. Your analysis is sound, and I certainly hope Judge Schiltz (everybody calls him Judge Schlitz, like the now-defunct beer that “made Milwaukee famous,” but he spells his name Schiltz) agrees with it and rules in favor of the plaintiffs, and against the net worth sweep. As we all keep saying, we only need to win one of these, and the SCOTUS opinion in SEC vs. Lucia clearly raised plaintiffs’ odds of winning the Bhatti case.

      Liked by 5 people

      1. Tim

        thanks! and yes, I admit to a misspent youth drinking cheap beer, and I have fixed the judge’s name.

        rolg

        Like

    2. ROLG,
      If Bhatti decision is to reverse the net worth sweep and the government appeals the decision, would the reversal of the net worth sweep be completed and Sr. Preferred stock retired or would they have to wait for the appeal decision? Also, thanks again for your analysis of the Bhatti case and the relevance of the appoint clause decision by SCOTUS to this case.

      Liked by 1 person

        1. ROLG,
          That’s what I thought so even if a positive decision, this could go on without resolution for awhile until all appeals exhausted. Thanks for the info…..

          Like

  3. Good Morning Tim,
    as we get close to the end of Mr Mel Watt term in the office of FHFA, I wonder how is the procedure to replace him. Has a new director to be confirmed by Congress before Watt steps out ? or can an acting director, appointed by the president, take over FHFA without being confirmed by Congress?
    In another words: is there any chance that Mr Watt continues running FHFA beyond Jan 1st?

    Like

    1. I’m not the expert on this, but I believe that if the president declines to reappoint Watt when his term expires he then can appoint a successor on an acting basis, pending confirmation by the Senate. But perhaps someone who knows how this process actually works can and will correct me.

      Like

      1. as I recall HERA permits director to name an acting director to replace him, pending potus nomination and senate confirmation (which was the handoff between Lockhart and Demarco)

        Liked by 1 person

  4. scotus ruled yesterday afternoon that SEC administrative law judges have been appointed in violation of the Appointments Clause. those cases that were adjudicated by unconstitutionally appointed SEC judges must be retried.

    if you read the transcript of judge schlitz in the bhatti oral argument, you heard him struggling with the remedy that he would have to grant were he to find that fhfa acting director Demarco was unconstitutionally appointed. (no senate confirm; acting in office >4 years). The remedy required of judge schlitz would be to invalidate NWS.

    this strong decision (7-2) should help him understand that a constitutional violation requires invalidation of the decision (NWS) made by the unconstitutionally appointed officer.

    Click to access 17-130_4f14.pdf

    Liked by 6 people

    1. I wouldn’t read too much into this. It is a very broad policy document from the administration’s Office of Management and Budget, with 34 “Government-wide Reorganization Proposals” covering a diverse range of issues and departments. The one that addresses Fannie and Freddie (“Reform Federal Role in Mortgage Finance,” beginning on page 75) is a summary of what’s been called “Corker-Warner 2.0,” that already has failed to generate any support in Congress.

      I suspect most followers of this blog now understand that policy in the Trump Administration is driven by the president, and influenced by a very small group of insiders. I doubt that whomever wrote the OMB document had access to either the president or Treasury Secretary Mnuchin when he or she put the mortgage finance section in it; they just wrote what seemed to be the most current idea circulating on Capitol Hill at the time (and is now outdated). We’re going to have to wait to hear from Mnuchin, or one of his key deputies, to learn what direction the administration wants to take in mortgage reform (I doubt the president will engage in or take the lead on this); anything prior to that will just be noise.

      By the way, I’ll be leaving on vacation tomorrow, so I may not be able to respond quickly to comments made over the next ten days or so.

      Liked by 1 person

      1. Tim

        I am a little more positive on this OMB piece. on the one hand, yes it is an omnibus “better government” piece that is and has been obligatory since VP Gore set out to fixing government after he invented the internet. so one can expect it to be likewise ignored upon delivery. yet this has none of the corker/mba liquidate/break up FnF casuistry. and best of all, the important pieces, exit from conservatorship and rebuild capital, do not need congressional approval. nothing wrong with a proposal that has a lot of nonessential items that require congressional approval if congress’s inaction can be anticipated.

        safe travels

        roll

        Like

  5. @peter

    while this analysis is so wrong it is hard to know where to begin, let me both begin and end by saying you have ignored treasury’s 80% warrant position. if you see this reply and then later tim deletes both your post and my reply, you will know why. i feel i must reply now however to make sure no one reads your post and relies upon it.

    rolg

    Like

  6. Hi Tim,
    I enjoy reading your comments regarding the GSEs. I have what I believe is a simple question, but one in which the answer has never been clear to me. It’s a basic “accounting” question regarding the conservatorship. IF (and I preface I’m not in the hopeful camp it will happen) the government determined they have been paid in full regarding the PSPA liquidation preference what would happen to the $120 billion senior preferred amount that currently sits on FNMA’s balance sheet as of March 31, 2018? I’m assuming there would be a debit entry to remove it, but what is the other side of the entry, what is the credit to? I’ve been in corporate finance and restructurings for over 25 years, but admittedly I’m not familiar with governmental accounting and was all most embarrassed to ask! Any light you can shed would be appreciated. Thank you, Jack

    Like

    1. Fannie publishes a consolidated balance sheet each quarter–both in its 10Q or 10K and near the end of its quarterly earnings press release. If you check either of those, you’ll see that at the end of the first quarter of 2018 the offset to the $120.8 billion in Treasury’s senior preferred stock is an entry called “accumulated deficit” (which at March 31, 2018 stood at $129.7 billion). Should Treasury’s senior preferred stock be declared paid in full or cancelled, the accumulated deficit entry would be reduced by an amount equal to the cancelled or deemed to be paid senior preferred, and there would be no net effect on total stockholders’ equity.

      Liked by 1 person

    1. while we await tim’s comment to the proposed rule, it seems to me that fhfa has made a good faith effort and analysis.

      just from a headline/30,000′ viewpoint, it points out that the proposed capital for fnma of $171B would have exceeded the FC cumulative losses of $167B. without getting into the details of whether all FC losses were actual or policy driven, how can anyone congressional member of an oversight committee say that this is insufficient?

      rolg

      Liked by 4 people

      1. I’ve just now downloaded FHFA’s notice of proposed rule making (NPR) on Fannie and Freddie capital. I’m very glad they’ve done this. I’ll read it as soon as I can (it’s 368 pages), and definitely will submit a comment on it. Comments are due 60 days after the NPR is published in the Federal Register, so I doubt I’ll have anything until sometime during July (I’m leaving for my trip to Iceland in ten days).

        Liked by 3 people

      2. tim

        here is what I need your help on. table 2, p. 69 states:

        Lifetime Single-Family Credit Losses on the Dec 31, 2007 Guarantee Portfolio using Current Acquisition Criteria* $21B 1.5%
        Proposed SF Credit Risk Capital Requirement using Current Acquisition Criteria* $30B 2.1% …Relative to Lifetime Credit Losses $9B 0.7%

        so if the capital requirement is tied to loans that the GSEs are currently permitted to securitize and guarantee, it seems the GSE capital requirement being proposed is much lower. I don’t understand if fhfa is proposing its rule to apply to current acquisition criteria, or to historical acquisition criteria.

        rolg

        Liked by 3 people

        1. I’ll want to read the entire document before I comment on parts of it. My intent is to go through it carefully as soon as I can, although with other current commitments I have I can’t give an estimate as to when I’ll be able to complete that review. I will, though, begin making blog comments on the FHFA capital proposal well before I submit my official comment to FHFA.

          Liked by 1 person

          1. Because this is most important stuff, I wish you could make your opinion known to Treasury, GSEs, FHFA, CMLA, Congress, etc.

            Liked by 1 person

          2. tim

            understood. and in my usual fashion i have raced through it to get the gist. my purpose is to see if what fhfa has proposed could be consistent with a moelis blueprint-type recapitalization.

            this is where i stand:

            fnma:

            risk based capital 9/2017: $115B table 5 p.72
            minimum leverage 2.5% assets: $83B table 7 p. 73
            minimum leverage bifurcated: $60B table 7 p. 73

            so i see the most stringent capital requirement under fhfa proposed rule as $115B for fnma (pro formo 9/2017). which seems obtainable by the capital markets, given the cash flows being generated.

            rolg

            Liked by 2 people

          3. the moelis blueprint envisioned $150-$180B of core capital (common and preferred stock) being raised for the GSEs in connection with its recapitalization proposal. of course, the feasibility of raising this amount in the capital markets has been enhanced given the GSE tax rate has been reduced by about one third since the blueprint release.

            the fhfa proposed rule’s most stringent capital requirement calls for $180B on a combined basis (table 5, p.72).

            Liked by 4 people

          4. I’m a little puzzled by this note from Josh. I generally agree with his overall assessment of the FHFA capital proposal—which he calls “a good start,” and “not being so onerous as to reduce the economic viability of their mandated mission to ensure liquidity to the primary mortgage market”—but he then spends the bulk of his piece objecting to the fact that “FHFA will not implement the capital requirements while the GSEs are in Conservatorship and will, instead, wait for Congress or the Administration to affirmatively act on GSE reform,” arguing that “Such a position is in direct opposition to the requirements of the HERA law and, again, ignores that Congress has acted and given it direction in the HERA law.”

            All of that is true. The problem is that Treasury and FHFA interpret HERA differently from how Josh does, and so far the Treasury/FHFA interpretation has prevailed in every court case decided to date. Fannie and Freddie cannot be recapitalized as long as the net worth sweep remains in force or until the conservatorship has ended, and FHFA cannot end either the sweep or the conservatorship without Treasury’s approval. For those reasons, I’ll take the half a loaf FHFA has given us: beginning a substantive dialogue about the right way to capitalize the companies post-conservatorship, if, whenever and however—i.e. legislatively or administratively—that happens.

            As I noted shortly after the FHFA capital proposal came out, I’m going to take my time going through and analyzing it before I write my comment letter (which I’ve got a couple of months to do). But I do have a preliminary reaction to it: it is extremely, and I would say unnecessarily, conservative. I’m going to withhold judgment as to whether the average 3.24 percent “estimated risk-based capital requirements as of September 31, 2017” for Fannie and Freddie shown in Table 1 of the summary document would make the companies “unviable” (I suspect not), but I will make arguments for how and why that number could be reduced without materially increasing taxpayer risk, and at the same time significantly lowering the cost and increasing the availability of mortgages to the large majority of homeowners Fannie and Freddie were chartered to serve.

            I recognize, of course, that there is a political dimension to the recapitalization of Fannie and Freddie, and that there will be some threshold capital percentage below which it will be very difficult to go, irrespective of the merits of the arguments for doing so. Building on the “Rule of Law Guy’s” observation, the range of dollar capital numbers for Fannie and Freddie as of September 2017 given in the FHFA summary table—from $154.1 billion without a deferred tax asset reserve to $180.9 billion with one—is virtually identical to the $155 to $180 capital range in the Moelis recapitalization plan released just over a year ago. I doubt this is coincidental, and it suggests we now are seeing some serious “fleshing out” of a pathway to administrative reform of the companies, if only for informational purposes. And it’s interesting that given the fundamentally high credit quality of the mortgages Fannie and Freddie finance, the only way to get to a 2.75 to 3.25 percent average capital number is to add a host of conservative buffers, a few of which are redundant. Hopefully some of those can be worked down as the discussion moves forward.

            Liked by 3 people

          5. @ tim

            there are two “check the box” aspects to the proposed rule.

            first, fhfa points out that the total capital required under the most stringent test is greater than FC cumulative losses. this is a nod to the senate banking committee and house financial services committee, saying this is a prudent rule given a “100 year flood” scenario.

            second, as you mention, this proposed rule is feasible insofar as the moelis blueprint intimates that it is confident capital in the range of this amount can be raised by the GSEs (even on pre-tax bill cash flows).

            whether any of this is intentional or serendipitous is a fielder’s choice. but i am pleased these boxes have been checked.

            rolg

            Liked by 2 people

      3. ROLG–Because most of them have no idea about the core issues or the GSE history and have little time to learn about the risk based capital naration and how and when the GSEs employed same.

        Or that the final government-approved GSE RBC product, way back when, was the result of a year plus back and forth between Tim Howard and Paul Volcker (who had by then retired from the federal government after his Fed Chairmanship and was a consultant), after TH–our blog host–spent months designing Fannie’s RBC model.
        Since the FHFA report is not a “one pager,” few in Congress iwll read it, but that won’t stop many from criticizing it for reasons we all hear from current know-nothings.

        Liked by 1 person

        1. I also doubt that anyone in Congress will personally read all 368 pages, but the summary is only 3 pages of text and 3 tables, easily digestible in just a few minutes. The fact that the last 100-odd pages give a template for Congress to work with, if not adopt wholesale, is a bonus.

          Liked by 2 people

          1. @midas/bill

            remember fhfa has the statutory authority under HERA to adopt this regulation. if there is to be an administrative solution, you are witnessing the writing of one more page of the roadmap. if this rule is adopted, fhfa and treasury “could” then decide to implement a recap financing strategy (think moelis blueprint) to position the GSEs to comply with the rule as a means to exit conservatorship. all of which might get congress of its duff.

            so congress can read this release or not as far as i care.

            rolg

            Liked by 3 people

  7. Tim,
    It has been a little bit since we’ve heard from you….can you review https://www.brookings.edu/research/shifting-the-risk-of-mortgage-defaults-from-taxpayers-to-investors/ when you have time and let us know your thoughts? I know you are critical of the CRTs due to the risk they can pose in times of stress and buyers not buying them despite the yield they might receive which ends up counter to the entire “process ” of truly transferring risk to the private sector. Is there a better way to actually transfer risk without having the model of tranches in your opinion? I understand and applaud your efforts for writing your book; it’s truly one of my favorites. Also can you address at some point your thoughts on whether or not there truly needs to be a government guarantee backstop or if there is adequate capital behind collective G-Fees and PMI to cover a catastrophic event? Penny for you thoughts and thank you for all you do.

    Liked by 1 person

    1. I’ve edited this comment, but thought I would use it to address why “it’s been a little bit since” I’ve posted or commented.

      I haven’t commented on the Brookings piece on CRTs because it didn’t say anything new about them, and I don’t have anything new or different to say about the article. I also don’t have anything new or different to say about whether there needs to (or should) be a government guaranty on conventional mortgages—I’ve discussed this issue at length and in detail both in posts and in previous answers to questions.

      I started this blog a little over two years ago because I believed I could use my knowledge and experience from Fannie Mae to inject verifiable facts and add informed analysis to a dialog on mortgage reform that I thought had become (and continues to be) dominated by misinformation and flimsy rationales for policy objectives supported not for their merits or workability but because they favor powerful constituencies. Since then I’ve been able to address most of the topics I’d identified when I began the blog; my positions on these topics—and my basis for and reasoning behind them—have been set forth and fully explained, and, through the archived posts on the blog, are available to anyone interested in them.

      The blog is now at a different stage of its evolution. It’s clear to me that the opinion leaders of what I call the Financial Establishment—who support mortgage reform that will benefit large banks and other influential interests, at the expense of higher costs and diminished availability of mortgages to low- and moderate-income homebuyers and increased risk to the financial system—by now are aware of the facts I’ve put out, and understand the arguments I am (and others are) making about the best way to reform the system. But they’ve been able to insulate themselves from the effects of these facts and arguments, because they’ve done such a good job getting the media to accept their invented versions of the problems of and solutions for the secondary market that they don’t feel they have to respond to challenges to their fictions; they can ignore them and not be called to account by anyone in a position to threaten their credibility. Repeating the same points over and over—whether in posts or in answers to comments—thus is of no benefit. If this battle is to be won, it won’t be because of a groundswell of public opinion; it will be because the right facts and arguments have reached and made an impression on those in a position to determine what reforms actually get implemented. That is a “behind the scenes” process that readers of this blog (or others) unfortunately can’t see.

      As to the blog itself, now that I’ve addressed the bulk of the issues I thought needed correction or clarification when I began it, future posts are most likely to be done in response to events, issues or new developments about which I think I might have something of value to add. The timing of those—and hence the blog posts associated with them—is not predictable. And while I will continue to respond to questions and comments, as I said in a note last year I will respond to them “selectively, based on whether I think the question, and the answer I have for it, will be of interest or informative to an audience that extends beyond the person who asked it.” All of this means there may be times when the blog is pretty quiet for a while. (And on that score, between the 24th of this month and early July I’ll be driving around Iceland in a Land Rover, and probably away from reliable internet for much of that time.)

      Liked by 3 people

      1. Tim, thanks for your reply. I understand your not wanting to comment unless it adds value to the whole beyond one person…I sincerely hope you enjoy your trip in Iceland and I too hope the “behind the scenes” process is underway and that in the future the truth will ultimately prevail.

        Liked by 1 person

      2. Win, lose or draw, your timely dissection of the “Congressional Wisdom” centered on GSE Reform has been a calming force, again, regardless of the outcome. Thanks for letting us vent.

        Bon Voyage, Tim.

        p.s. If you want to recreate your Icelandic excursion after the fact, hop on to Montreal and you can whip around in my Supercharged RR between November and March, same driving conditions, better food 🙂

        Liked by 1 person

  8. tim

    i encourage you and your readers to read the hindes/jacobs reply brief in the 3rd circuit:

    https://www.dropbox.com/s/b8b4p333o0hmmru/Document.pdf?dl=0

    while it is strong throughout, it is particularly noteworthy in that it refers to an admission made by treasury counsel in the saxton appellate oral argument that it “might” be ultra vires for fhfa as conservator to cause FnF to violate their charters (her example in saxton was if FnF were to originate loans). see p. 9.

    hindes/jacobs is arguing that because the NWS violates delaware corporate law (and therefore the charter of any delaware corporation that issues it), it is ultra vires and therefore HERA’s anti-injunction bar does not apply. this would permit a court to entertain jurisdiction and void the NWS if it finds that the NWS in fact violates delaware corporate law.

    i would hope that hindes/jacobs counsel hammers fhfa and treasury in oral argument before the 3rd circuit (which hindes/jacobs has requested that the 3rd circuit hold) about the saxton admission, to make it clear that treasury counsel has already conceded that fhfa as conservator cannot use the anti-injunction to preclude a federal court from determining whether the NWS is a valid-issued security. and if fhfa/treasury counsels don’t concede that in hindes/jacobs oral argument, how exactly would they now resist this conclusion.

    rolg

    Liked by 4 people

    1. I agree that the Jacobs-Hindes reply brief is very well argued, and that its reference to Treasury’s own statement in the Saxton oral argument as to what constitutes ultra vires activity for FHFA is a strong point. It’s an unfortunate fact that in all of the net worth sweep cases, plaintiffs’ counsel has to make nearly ironclad arguments to have a chance of a ruling in their favor, given the clear reluctance of the judges in these cases to find against the government in a $100 billion-plus lawsuit. Yet the shear number of cases being filed, under various theories of law, works in plaintiffs’ favor. As the plaintiffs’ briefs get better and better, as here, the odds continually rise that in at least one of these cases either a lower court or an appellate court will find itself unable to come up with a rationale for ignoring such obvious evidence of premeditated and unlawful wrongdoing on the part of Treasury and FHFA in expropriating, without compensation, the assets of two shareholder-owned companies for its own financial and policy purposes.

      Liked by 6 people

        1. @bird

          i am in your camp, bird.

          @tim

          the most obvious way for govt to win hindes/jacobs is for merits panel to find that HERA preempts state law with respect to what determines whether FnF has issued a valid security while in conservatorship. federal preemption is discussed in reply brief and there would appear to be no grounds for merits panel to find preemption. it is not like HERA said that the conservator has authority to issue securities having terms at odds with governing state corporation law.

          but i am hopeful that first, 3rd circuit sets case for oral argument, and then hindes/jacobs pounds away during their opening oral argument at proposition that defendants have already agreed that violating the FnF charter is ultra vires action by fhfa as conservator. just pounds away at it…and when fhfa/treasury counsel stand to argue, one would hope a judge simply asks, “well counsel, what do you have to say to what Ps have to say about violating charter being ultra vires for conservator?” it wont be an easy rebuttal for them.

          rolg

          Liked by 3 people

      1. Tim,

        Thanks for your work and great comments / informative blog.

        I am not a lawyer, but the Jacobs-Hindes Reply Brief seems to touch on these three points in its text, among other things:

        1. NWS should be voided;
        2. Concept of illegal Takings; and,
        3. The Senior Preferred should never have been issued.

        “Here, FHFA’s actions directly violated those very state law charters by issuing stock with terms not permitted under the governing state laws. Thus, the acts were ultra vires. Even if FHFA were correct that it was acting in the Companies’ interest (a specious proposition), such acts are Case: 17-3794 Document: 003112939803 Page: 17 Date Filed: 05/24/2018

        10 nevertheless outside the powers HERA grants because they are not within the Companies’ own limits on their power. This is precisely the situation Treasury confesses Section 4617(f) would not protect.”

        This seems to be the first case that I am aware of that argues all three major issues. This argument appears well thought out and supported. I hope that the court will find merit in the Reply Brief. Any further comments?

        Again, thank you.

        IAmJ_1

        Liked by 1 person

        1. No, other than to reiterate that I always have felt the Delaware suit was the cleanest and most straightforward challenge to the net worth sweep–with its claim that sweeping all of Fannie and Freddie’s profits to Treasury, foreclosing the possibility of dividends to any other class of shareholder, is an illegal feature of the senior preferred stock under Delaware and Virginia law, making the net worth sweep void and unenforceable–and the reply brief adds valuable legal arguments in support of this core point.

          Liked by 1 person

  9. Tim and Rolg
    Good evening. Did you have a chance to read the new complaint filed by Joshua Angel, a well known corporate specialized lawyer acting on his own?

    Like

    1. @j b

      waste of time. one claim is breach of government’s implicit guaranty. btw, i have never heard of him.

      rolg

      Like

      1. As ROLG noted, the basis for Mr. Angel’s suit is a claim that Fannie and Freddie junior preferred stock carries a “Federal Government implicit guaranty” of dividend and principal payments that the Third Amendment violates.

        Angel first raised this issue two years ago in a paper titled “Government Perfidy and the Mismanagement of the GSEs in Conservatorship.” On March 1, 2016 he sent this paper to the Fannie and Freddie boards, requesting that they “seek and obtain clarification from outside counsel” on his claim, adding that, “I have engaged counsel to commence suit against you and the Company for class redress for breach of duty and breach of contract.” In a subsequent letter to the companies’ boards dated April 19, 2016, Angel reiterated his threat to sue, and attached a draft complaint. I read that complaint and recall thinking at the time, “that’s a real long shot.” He finally filed his suit (rewritten but substantially similar in content) this past Monday, and I still feel the same way about its prospects.

        Liked by 1 person

  10. tim

    i found this reference in footnote 2 to a table in the regulatory capital footnote 12 (F-55) in the fnma 2017 10K:

    Statutory minimum capital requirement(2)

    __________

    (2) Generally, the sum of (a) 2.50% of on-balance sheet assets, except those underlying Fannie Mae MBS held by third parties; (b) 0.45% of the unpaid principal balance of outstanding Fannie Mae MBS held by third parties; and (c) up to 0.45% of other off-balance sheet obligations, which may be adjusted by the Director of FHFA under certain circumstances.

    leaving aside the off-BS items, this 2.5% of BS asset requirement seems sensible to me, and i assume it has been adjusted upward since the FC. i realize you have stated that fhfa needs to do a real world risk-based analysis, as instructed by HERA, which it hasnt done yet. but wouldnt 2.5% be a capital requirement that would balance well the interests of the taxpayer in minimizing risk exposure and the interest of the homeowner in paying a non-inflated guaranty fee?

    thanks

    rolg

    Liked by 1 person

    1. speaking of which, just saw this item re watts’ testimony today before senate banking committee:

      “The FHFA director also said the agency is planning to propose a risk-based capital and minimum leverage capital rule for the GSEs that would replace the standards in place prior to the conservatorship. While the rule would be suspended while the GSEs are in conservatorship, Watt said it’s important for the agency to propose a rule based on current operations.”

      Liked by 2 people

      1. The risk-based capital and minimum leverage ratios would be an excellent step; I hope that as FHFA does these it is transparent as to the process it is following. It needs to be based on some defined stress environment, and be clear (and reasonable) about the treatment of guaranty fees and admin expenses during the course of the test. It’s really not hard to do properly, if that indeed is FHFA’s intent. (My concern is that, as with the Dodd-Frank stress test FHFA runs each year, Treasury insists that FHFA follow a methodology that effectively backs into the “bank-like” capital number supporters of the banks would like to see).

        On your first comment, the 2.50% on-balance sheet capital number and the 0.45% off-balance sheet number are the minimums from the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act of 1992; they have not been updated since the crisis.

        Liked by 1 person

        1. ICBA Statement on Capital Proposal from FHFA Director Mel Watt

          Washington, D.C (May 24, 2018)—Independent Community Bankers of America® (ICBA) President and CEO Rebeca Romero Rainey issued the following statement on a proposal from Federal Housing Finance Agency Director Mel Watt to develop new risk-based and minimum-leverage capital rules for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.

          “ICBA strongly supports FHFA Director Mel Watt’s comments regarding the development of a new risk-based capital and minimum-leverage capital rule for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. ICBA has vocally urged Director Watt to require the government-sponsored enterprises to develop and implement a recapitalization plan, as required by the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008. Establishing these capital standards for both GSEs is the first step in that process, which ICBA hopes will eventually lead to their full recapitalization.

          “Only a strongly capitalized secondary market can protect taxpayers and provide the liquidity needed to support the mortgage market. Community banks count on the liquidity that the GSEs provide to help meet the home-lending needs of their communities. ICBA looks forward to continuing to work with policymakers to ensure housing-finance reform meets the needs of all borrowers and lenders.”

          Liked by 2 people

      2. I know it’s hard for a bunch of lawyers to fathom, but maybe you shouldn’t make a law about the best % of risk and instead let the equity markets decide if the companies are properly managing for risk…

        when all you have is a hammer, everything looks like a nail.

        Like

          1. Were there no regulations in place then? Do we think the people who created CDO cubed are going to be stopped by a law? I have my doubts.

            Further, not much has structurally changed since then, we’ve just got more debt in the system in different areas! Should be fun when it unwinds.

            Liked by 1 person

  11. Tim –

    FHFA may have heard your comments on Credit Risk Transfers.

    Direct quote from the their report released today:

    “Moreover, initiatives such as credit risk transfer transactions confer risk management benefits but impose costs that could reduce Enterprise earnings.”

    “Header: Barriers to Investor Participation in Credit Risk Transfer Transactions
    Body: This credit risk transfer market is relatively new and evolving and relies on ongoing investor interest and ability to purchase the credit risk. FHFA has previously identified several statutory impediments which, if addressed, could avoid unintended consequences for some types of investors and thus help to expand investor participation in Enterprise credit risk transfer transactions.
    FHFA continues to believe that these statutory impediments should be removed.”

    Full link to the report:

    Click to access FHFA_2017_Report-to-Congress.pdf

    Liked by 1 person

    1. This is all pretty general. And FHFA still hasn’t addressed the fundamental problem that exists with securitized CRTs: if investors only buy them when they expect to make an attractive return on the capital they invest–i.e., when their combined interest payments and return of principal comfortably exceed any credit losses they expect to have transferred to them–how could issuance of these securities ever be effective for Fannie and Freddie as a means of managing their credit risk?

      Liked by 2 people

  12. Tim,

    Good morning. I wanted to get your thoughts on this new piece of information, as the Treasury has been mostly tight-lipped regarding future plans.

    As always, thank you.

    Like

    1. more of phillips today:

      Treasury Official Sees Major Impact from Single Security
      By John Bancroft

      jbancroft@imfpubs.com

      A key Treasury Department official suggested that issuers of non-agency MBS may someday participate in the common securitization platform being developed by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.

      Craig Phillips, counselor to the Treasury, said the industry has made a lot of progress toward the launch of the single security that is scheduled for June 2019. “Industry preparedness is about an eight or nine on a scale of 10,” he said during remarks at this week’s secondary market conference sponsored by the Mortgage Bankers Association in New York.

      Phillips characterized the CSP as “reform-agnostic,” suggesting that it will be an important part of the MBS infrastructure regardless of how Fannie and Freddie are eventually reformed. While the platform is currently owned by a joint venture between Fannie and Freddie, the Treasury official said issuers of non-agency MBS may someday be able to invest in the venture and use the platform.

      Treasury wants to encourage the growth of the non-agency MBS market through regulatory reform, Phillips said. That includes streamlining disclosure rules and overhauling bank capital rules that discourage participation.

      ***

      one of the nagging little problems of the private label securitizations done before the financial crisis was that all of the documentation was “standard” but not really “uniform”. meaning, if you were buying PLS mbs, unless you read the docs you couldnt be sure there wasnt a weird term in the docs that might affect the waterfall in ways that you did not understand. no investors really read the docs since they thought if they bought enough mbs, the diversification would net out any anomalies that may be in a particular underlying doc.

      it is no surprise that phillips, who used to run morgan stanley’s mbs desk, would be in favor of a single mbs security governing not just FnF but also all bank securitizations that may be done down the road. just as a treasury security is fungible except for maturity and interest rate, so will be all mbs (assuming there is a fed backstop to all mbs…although a FnF guaranty will achieve better pricing than any private label mbs that is just relying on internal pool credit support). and it sounds like FnF might even get paid a fee for the use of the platform…wouldnt that be a surprise!

      rolg

      Liked by 1 person

      1. There’s nothing new in any of Phillips’ comments. The common securitization platform (CSP) is being built as a utility, currently to accommodate the securitization of Fannie MBS and Freddie PCs, but potentially to be used by other security issuers as well. As Phillips says, for the latter to happen will require a directive either by Congress or the administration (with the latter likely triggering additional lawsuits). Since the CSP project as it stands now benefits Freddie at the expense of Fannie, I’d been expecting to see suits from Fannie shareholders challenging it; I suspect the reason we haven’t has to do with the lack of success to date in plaintiffs’ lawsuits against the net worth sweep.

        Liked by 2 people

  13. Perry Cap. LLC v. Mnuchin, 848 F.3d 1072 (D.C. Cir. 2017) (Brown, J. dissenting in part)

    “I cannot conclude the anti-injunction provision protects FHFA’s actions here or, more generally, endorses FHFA’s stunningly broad view of its own power. Plaintiffs — not all innocent and ill-informed investors, to be sure — are betting the rule of law will prevail. In this country, everyone is entitled to win that bet.”

    The LAST sentence hits other judges really hard. I think that as a judge of many years, she read their mind.

    Liked by 4 people

  14. for ROLG or anyone else, Does anyone know the last time Chuck cooper, argued in court? The Saxton case in district was previously argued by a different attorney. Is it typical to change up the litigator on appeal?

    Like

    1. @elliot

      he who pays, says.

      any trial depends upon discovery of facts more than perry mason dramatics, and there already has been developed a thorough set of facts in the court of claims action, which is available to all counsel who sign a confidentiality agreement. if the litigated claim is treasury coercion over fhfa at time of signing of NWS, i could see additional depositions relating to who did what to whom at that time relating to that event.

      but the firm which probably has the best handle on the facts pattern at time of NWS is cooper’s firm.

      rolg

      Liked by 1 person

  15. Dear Tim
    Good afternoon. I have been listening for, at least, a couple of years the arguments about the difference between “may” and “shall” in legal instruments. So far several judges concluded that “May” is permissive and “Shall” is mandatory, and then they think that FHFA has the “option” of restoring the companies to sound financial shape.
    But, I wonder if anyone argued that Congress could not have used “Shall” and was forced to use “May” because it could not be mandatory for FHFA to achieve a result that did not depend only on its will. I mean you cannot make mandatory for an entity to be successful in business because it depends on many factors that are out of the control of that entity. Such factors are market conditions, competition, natural disasters, economy in the rest of the world , etcetera.
    Stepping in the shoes of Congress, one can say: “you may succeed putting the companies in solvent condition, or you should try to put the companies in solvent condition”. But, again stepping in the shoes of Congress, one cannot say: “you shall succeed in this business”. This is because of the uncertain nature of business and because of the factors that FHFA cannot control.
    I wonder if “may’ instead of used as permissive was , in fact, used as and expression of possibility.
    Do you know if this point was made by plaintiffs?
    Thanks for your work fighting for the true on this sad chapter of US judicial history.

    Liked by 2 people

    1. J Barnes,

      Judge Brown in dissent addresses this.

      “The Court makes much of the statute’s statement that a
      conservator “may” take action to operate the company in a sound
      and solvent condition and preserve and conserve its assets while a
      receiver “shall” liquidate the company. It concludes the statute
      permits, but does not compel in any judicially enforceable sense,
      FHFA to preserve and conserve Fannie’s and Freddie’s assets
      however it sees fit. See Op. 21–25. I disagree. Rather, read in the
      context of the larger statute—especially the specifically defined
      powers of a conservator and receiver set forth in Subsections
      4617(b)(2)(D) and (b)(2)(E)—Congress’s decision to use
      permissive language with respect to a conservator’s duties is best
      understood as a simple concession to the practical reality that a
      conservator may not always succeed in rehabilitating its ward. The
      statute wisely acknowledges that it is “not in the power of any man
      to command success” and does not convert failure into a legal
      wrong. See Letter from George Washington to Benedict Arnold
      (Dec. 5, 1775), in 3 THE WRITINGS OF GEORGE WASHINGTON, 192
      (Jared Sparks, ed., 1834). Of course, this does not mean the
      Agency may affirmatively sabotage the Companies’ recovery by
      confiscating their assets quarterly to ensure they cannot pay off
      their crippling indebtedness. There is a vast difference between
      recognizing that flexibility is necessary to permit a conservator to
      address evolving circumstances and authorizing a conservator to
      undermine the interests and destroy the assets of its ward without
      meaningful limit.”

      (page. 83- https://www.cadc.uscourts.gov/internet/opinions.nsf/66A4E1FEF4BB8401852580CE005620C3/$file/14-5243-1662090.pdf)

      Liked by 1 person

    2. “But, I wonder if anyone argued that Congress could not have used “Shall” and was forced to use “May” because it could not be mandatory for FHFA to achieve a result that did not depend only on its will.”

      this is exactly what judge brown wrote in her dissent in perry.

      Liked by 2 people

      1. Cooper offered a different argument: (1) showing an instance of ‘may’ elsewhere in HERA where if the action wasn’t performed by choice it would be absurd and (2) that ‘may’ can mean ‘is allowed to’.

        Like

        1. if you listen to the saxton oral argument, both cooper and the 8th circuit judges referred to an 8th circuit case, cedarminn. while the holding was unrelated (relating to timeliness of a conservator’s or receiver’s rejection of a burdensome lease), there is language in the case that made clear that the 8th circuit in that case thought the conservator (under FIRREA with the same exact “may” language as HERA) was required to preserve and conserve assets….which is what the conservator turned receiver in cedarminn was doing…rejecting an uneconomic release in order to preserve and conserve assets.

          now fhfa and treasury counsel argued that this language was tangential to the holding in the case (they didnt use the word “dicta” but that was their point), but the judges seemed to think that Ps were appropriately arguing the cedarminn case to the effect that the 8th circuit has precedent that “may” is not discretionary in the manner that the other circuits had found.

          rolg

          Liked by 2 people

          1. I finally have been able to listen to the Saxton oral argument. I think that overall Chuck Cooper did an excellent job representing plaintiffs’ position–particularly his emphasis on the importance of having an opportunity to explore the factual record at trial in order to determine whether FHFA/Treasury’s actions were ultra vires (rather than allowing a judge to conclude that they weren’t based on Treasury and FHFA’s egregious and unrebutted misrepresentations of that record in their filings and arguments). Still, I wish Cooper had found a way to make the same point about “may” versus “shall” that judge Brown did in her dissent: whereas you can say a receiver “shall” liquidate a company, you can’t say that a conservator “shall” rehabilitate a company because it may not be possible to do so. That’s such a simple and powerful concept, and in my view it makes the government’s interpretation of HERA–that Congress intended “may” to mean that FHFA acting as conservator can do whatever it wants with Fannie and Freddie, with no definable boundaries (at least the Saxton judges were unable to elicit any from the government’s lawyers)–ludicrous by comparison.

            Liked by 4 people

          2. Tim/ROLG
            Is there any other lawsuit where the dissent of Judge Brown can be used as argument on the interpretation of “may” and “shall” on the issue of NWS based on the statute of HERA.. I am not a lawyer but the interpretatioin/ position of Judge Brown and your interpretations makes a compelling argument for the plaintiffs. In the revised filing of plaintiff in Judge Sweeney’s court did they include NWS as illegal and unconstitutional?
            Thanks a lot for all your hard work.

            Like

          3. @anon/tim

            there is a certain amount of weakness in arguing to a new court that the dissent had it right in a previous court. i admit the logic of the use of may in the case of a mission that can’t be guaranteed to be successful is powerful, and frankly i think cooper did use this logic in an altered fashion in his briefing and argument when he said that the conservator cannot “abandon the conservator’s mission” to preserve and conserve…another way of saying the preserve/conserve mission is obligatory even if the word may is not.

            cooper took a calculated chance in his reply brief to focus on the 8th circuit cerdarminn case (https://law.justia.com/cases/federal/appellate-courts/F2/956/1446/326280/) where you will find this language:

            “Fourth, the importance of retaining an independent right to repudiate contracts is exemplified by the distinct missions of the conservator and receiver. That Congress intended conservators and receivers to have different missions is clear. RTC as conservator of a failed institution was empowered to take action necessary to restore the failed thrift to a solvent position and “to carry on the business of the institution and preserve and conserve the assets and property of the institution.” 12 U.S.C.A. § 1821(d) (2) (D). As receiver, on the other hand, RTC was empowered to liquidate the institution.”

            so without getting bogged down parsing the relative permissiveness of the word may, cooper used this 8th circuit acknowledgement of a conservator’s “mission” as the touchstone for his argument.

            when you add this language in a case, that at least one judge thought distinguished the 8th circuit from the other circuits which have found in favor of fhfa, to the concern raised twice by the panel that this understanding of “may” resulted in the nationalization of FnF, then you have an oral argument that cooper is likely to be pleased with.

            rolg

            Liked by 1 person

          4. I wasn’t suggesting that Cooper refer to the language in judge Brown’s dissent; just that he make the same point as she did about “may” versus “shall” in this context. The government is winning net worth sweep cases it shouldn’t be winning, and it is doing so by making very simple (albeit incorrect, and often inaccurate) arguments, and repeating them. Plaintiffs counsel, in my reading, has been making more logical legal arguments and losing. I’m not suggesting they abandon their logical or nuanced arguments, but I do think supplementing them with some simple and clear ones on key aspects of the case would be well advised.

            Liked by 2 people

        2. @tim

          judges at two times asked defendants’ counsel if this is a case of “not worth anything then, not worth anything now,” but shareholders are still paying for the shares. D counsel did not know how to react (at one point cayne said he was thinking he would stick to the legal issues), and i am not sure where the judge was going with this: cynicism it seems, but directed at Ps or Ds?

          but for a fact pattern that smells bad, yes perhaps Ps counsel might direct the judges’ attention more to the bigger picture, and beyond the dictionary definition of a single word..

          rolg

          Like

          1. I know that plaintiffs counsel is frustrated with how both the government and the courts have been treating the facts in this case. At this stage of the proceedings–which is a motion to dismiss–the courts are duty-bound to take plaintiffs’ statement of facts as true. But they clearly are not; many of the judges’ questions are couched in the context of the “bad facts” the government has succeeded in injecting inappropriately into this case. It’s possible that plaintiffs counsel is being too literal in adhering to the “basic principle that every first year law student has been taught” of taking plaintiffs’ statement of facts as true in adjudicating a motion to dismiss, but I don’t know what other realistic alternative it has. The government isn’t playing by the rules, and the judges are letting it get away with that.

            Liked by 1 person

      2. Brown is correct in her conclusion but not in her logic.

        The use of “may” does not have in any prima facie sense the import of the possibility of not succeeding. In other words, it’s not cogent to argue that “may” was used instead of “shall” in order to acknowledge the reality that it might be impossible to restore the entities to a sound and solvent position. Her reasoning was, since conservator might not be able to restore the GSEs, it couldn’t be said that the conservative “shall” save them.

        I think she was lead down the garden path. Consider, “may” merely means that it’s permissible that the conservator run the business to that end, one of solvency. That is, the conservator is permitted to do what is necessary to restore the GSEs. Such a prima facie interpretation is narrow. Single propositions usually are!

        “May” does not address what the the conservator *may not* do. Accordingly, it’s logically fallacious for defendant(s) to argue: since FHFA may conserve assets, it needn’t conserve assets. NOTE: That’s an argument from silence that takes on an enormous burden of proof. That my sixteen year old “may” go out with her friends tonight does not imply she may also stay home and raid dad’s wine cellar. To find out what the conservator may not do, we have to look elsewhere. It’s not implied by “may.” A better analogy might be, “you may water the garden while I’m away.” From that proposition we cannot rationally deduce that permission has been granted to do other things, like having a party for instance. But even more glaringly, we surely may not deduce that in addition to watering the garden, you may also mow over and destroy the garden!

        Liked by 1 person

        1. @ron

          there is a legal phrase, bad facts make bad law.

          for many years “may” has been associated with what statutory conservators do, without controversy because conservators were trying to conserve and preserve. no bad acting conservators, no bad facts.

          here comes a coerced conservator and a bad fact pattern, a conservator trying to accomplish a treasury-directed policy objective of shutting down FnF, and shoehorn it into the word “may”…hence the bad law relating to what “may” means that is perry and the other misguided APA decisions.

          rolg

          Liked by 1 person

        2. Agree!

          “You may stand up” does not imply “You are allowed sit down” or “you are allowed lie down” or “you are allowed to eat” or anything else.

          I think cooper has this covered in a new filing in the Saxton case:

          “When Congress says that an agency “may” do one thing, it does not
          simultaneously give the agency license to do the opposite. “

          Liked by 4 people

          1. there is an interesting interplay between saxon in 8th cir and bhatti (federal district court within 8th circuit). judge schlitz is hearing 3 principal claims in bhatti: unconstitutional structure of fhfa (which he appears to think little of as per oral argument), appointments clause violation where acting director demarco acted over 4 years of his 5 year term without presidential appointment and senate consent (which he thought more highly of), and an unconstitutional delegation argument (if “may” means that a fhfa director can do anything while acting as conservator, then this is an unconstitutional delegation by congress of legislative power to an agency).

            the unconstitutional delegation argument means that even if saxton panel find that may means what perry etc have found it to mean, judge schlitz may find that this judicial reading affords the fhfa director too much discretion. now, whether schlitz waits for the saxton court to rule first on the meaning of “may” or not is hard to say, especially since he can rule on the other two claims, which were not argued in saxton before the 8th circuit.

            rolg

            Liked by 1 person

      1. Correct Mark.

        “Congress … does not alter the fundamental details of a regulatory scheme in vague terms or ancillary provisions–it does not, one might say, hide elephants in mouseholes.” Whitman v. American Trucking Association, 531 U.S. 457, 468 (2001). This doctrine is an exception to the textualism approach to constitutional interpretation.

        Like

  16. Tim,

    Good morning. It’s no secret that Jim Parrott of the Urban Institute has #TBTF bank clients. As a matter of fact, just this morning, Josh Rosner claimed to have heard it straight from the mouth of the horse that Bank of America had Parrott on payroll. Why is it that the Urban Institute, if wanting to be taken seriously in the mortgage reform discussions, isn’t required to disclose which #TBTF banks are influencing their opinions from a financial standpoint?

    As always, thank you.

    Like

      1. As I mentioned I would, I’ve gone after this issue as well, on a somewhat different tack from Josh’s. I sent a note to a senior person in the Urban Institute hierarchy calling attention to and giving my critique of the latest Parrot-Zandi piece, quoting from the comment I made about it on my blog and also pointing out that it repeats Treasury’s fictitious rationale for the net worth sweep, notwithstanding the fact that discovery in the Court of Federal Claims has unearthed numerous communications from Parrott admitting the real reasons for it—to keep Fannie and Freddie from recapitalizing and to perpetuate the conservatorships. I concluded my note by saying, “My reason for writing isn’t to complain about the paper, but to make sure the leadership of the Urban Institute knows its name is on a deliberately slanted (in my view) and knowingly inaccurate advocacy piece. I suspect that’s something the Urban Institute neither wants nor supports.”

        The person to whom I wrote acknowledged the legitimacy of the criticism and said they would “take this up.” So I know the Urban Institute’s leadership is aware of and I believe now focused on this issue.

        Liked by 4 people

  17. Sorry I see Rule-of-Law already posted. I would be a shame and sham if the American court system does not allow at least one trial out of the many cases dismissed when the case is of this stature and with good cause and merit. Just would not be America if all cases were dismissed. plaintiff deserves its day in court!

    Like

  18. Sure liked what I heard in the Saxton hearing. Judges were clearly open to the possibility that the 3rd amendment was ultra vires. Also would guess that Cooper’s last utterance, ‘Surely I get to try these matters!’ was a good conclusion and fell on sympathetic ears. Let’s hope.

    Liked by 2 people

    1. http://media-oa.ca8.uscourts.gov/OAaudio/2018/5/171727.MP3 to hear the transcript.

      this was a promising oral argument…as was perry, so caution is in order.

      this was the first time that i recall that the non-legal point was made by a judge that, my golly, the NWS “nationalized” these companies. finally a judge was (one hopefully assumes) finally concerned that a conservatorship/receivership statute was converted into a nationalization statute without clear authority from congress…sort of an astounding premise that those so advanced in the legal community to become federal appellate judges normally overlook.

      cooper for Ps was excellent, cayne for fhfa meh, and wright for treasury, dont get me started.

      net net, the judges were troubled by the extent of fhfa/treasury claim that any act pursuant to a conservator power was authorized even if antithetical to the conservator purpose.

      at least these judges were independent thinkers. we shall see.

      rolg

      Liked by 2 people

      1. just a tidbit addendum if i may on saxtion oral argument in 8th circuit.

        at one point, a male judge (stras or benton) asks cayne for fhfa to react to what the judge refers to as the Ps strongest point, that fhfa was under the direction of treasury in direct contravention of HERA.

        in his reply, cayne states that he has never considered this to be a strong point for Ps at all. rule #1…never gratuitously contradict the judge. of course, cite alternative authority, make a counterargument, but never say to a judge, in effect, you’re off base. all cayne said was, gee there was a two-party negotiation, and the NWS was the arms-length result…which of course is a question of fact.

        given Ps well-pled complaint, cooper reiterated in rebuttal that surely he had the opportunity to prove at trial whether fhfa was improperly under treasury’s direction…that very question of fact the male judge seemed interested in.

        so again, for fear of reading too much into the oral argument, this sounded like there is at least one judge who thought Ps should go to trial on fact question whether fhfa was improperly under direction of treasury.

        rolg

        Liked by 3 people

        1. supplementary tidbit addendum if i may.

          when you listen to the saxton oral argument, fhfa counsel cayne starts his argument, as he should, with recitation of the three other circuit courts that have rejected P’s APA claim that fhfa exceeded its authority as conservator.

          and then you hear a male judge cut cayne off and say in effect, yes, but now mr. cayne you come to the 8th circuit and you must now confront our 8th circuit case, CedarMinn.

          CedarMinn, construing FIRREA, upon which HERA is based (and in material part copies verbatim), is a 1992 case that has favorable language for Ps insofar as it speaks of the statutory conservator’s “mission” and “duties” as in “parallel” with the common law conservator. (the perry majority rejects use of common law conservator duties to inform what fhfa as conservator “may” do).

          to see how Ps are trying to use CedarMinn, see saxton Ps reply brief: http://gselinks.com/Court_Filings/Saxton/17-1727-0020.pdf

          @p.7 ” This Court’s decision in RTC v. CedarMinn Building Limited Partnership could not be more clear: a conservator’s “mission[ ]” is “to take action necessary to restore the failed [financial institution] to a solvent position and ‘to carry on the business of the institution and preserve and conserve the assets and property of the institution.’ ” 956 F.2d 1446, 1453 (8th Cir. 1992) (quoting 12 U.S.C.
          § 1821(d)(2)(D)).”

          cayne tried to distinguish CedarMinn, and the judges didnt seem all that eager to go down cayne’s path. how much CedarMinn informs the judges view on saxton is the wildcard in this case, as the other circuits have no reason to accord an 8th circuit case with any particular precedential value, unlike the 8th circuit itself.

          rolg

          Liked by 1 person

  19. i have never seen this before, and i am not sure what the 5th circuit will do with collins, but the 5th circuit accepted on an interlocutory appeal the all-american case, alleging that the cfpb is unconstitutionally structured.

    collins had oral argument awhile back, and Ps asserted two claims: that the NWS violates HERA under APA (like perry), and that fhfa is unconstitutionally structured. the fhfa and cfpb are very similarly structured, with fhfa director even more independent arguably because of HERA’s anti-injunction bar.

    so essentially the same claim is at issue in the same circuit in two different cases at the same time. you would expect some sort of coordination at the instance of the chief judge, and since collins was argued already, collins should come first…and yet a merits panel decision in collins on the constitutional claim may not be agreeable to all of the other 5th cir judges, including those who will comprise the merits panel in all-american. one possibility is that collins is put on hold and all-american goes to briefing and argument en banc (or collins is reargued en banc).

    of course if the collins merits panel rules in favor or against Ps on APA claim, then that could come down with the constitutionality claim held in abeyance. who knows.

    ted olson is on briefing on all american and will likely argue.

    rolg

    Liked by 2 people

    1. 1. Dico Akseraylian, a spokesman for PHH, confirmed that the company did not petition the Supreme Court.

      2. Judge Shiltz may be praying the 5th Circuit to do something similar to that done by DC Circuit. Otherwise he would have to rule the organization of FHFA was unconstitutional. (by Appointment clause)

      3. Single director problem is far more worse. If unconstitutional, the original C-ship is voided.

      4. Arguments by Judges Henderson and Cavanaugh were more powerful, may find friendlier ears in 5th circuit.

      Like

      1. @mark

        1. the appeal was granted in all-american some 3 days before the PHH cert petition needed to be made. PHH won reversal of penalty based on statute, didnt need to pursue unconstitutionalilty structured claim. ted olson on both cases. i can see olson saying to PHH that you dont have to pay my fee for a cert request if i am going to argue claim again in a circuit other than DC.

        2. judge schlitz will have to decide the (strong) appointments clause claim at some point since not raised in collins.

        3. single director claim is arguably worse for Ps in front of judge schlitz as well. in the oral arg transcript, you can see his dislike of a remedy that would invalidate everything fhfa has done since demarco and before watt (even though collins P just focused on NWS). appointments clause claim remedy (assuming bright line remedy of 2 year cutoff borrowed from recess appointments clause in const) would invalidate NWS but not PSPA and first two amendments.

        4. as is judge brown’s dissent in perry. we shall see.

        rolg

        Liked by 2 people

  20. Hello Tim, years ago when you released the Mortgage Wars, you held a talk at Politics & Prose bookstore in DC. (Here’s a link to those who want to see video https://youtu.be/kQAKx9nXg7g)

    Tim, are you considering doing another solo talk/lecture? The event itself would draw key industry insiders and would spark great discussions.

    Liked by 1 person

    1. I hadn’t considered a talk or lecture, but I’d now be more inclined to appear at events discussing the follow-on to the “mortgage wars,” which is really how I view the last ten years of the banks trying to take over Fannie and Freddie’s business, for their own competitive benefit and for made-up reasons that are readily rebuttable. The banks have done a very thorough job of cementing their fictional view of the causes of and remedies for the financial crisis in the media, the Congress, the mind of the general public and even, it seems, the court system. Those of us who know what actually happened–and what needs to be done to create a future mortgage finance system that works for homebuyers and not the banks–need to do a much better job communicating these things to those in a position to make a difference in the reform process.

      Liked by 3 people

      1. tim

        would you have any interest in meeting with, for example, a member of the house financial services committee? if so, perhaps you can email me with your contact info and i might be able to set that up.

        rolg

        Liked by 4 people

  21. Jim Parrott and Mark Zandi published another paper about the GSEs. It seems to try to address arguments for release from conservatorship, scaling back CRTs, etc.

    Click to access gse_reform_is_dead_long_live_gse_reform_2.pdf

    Is any of this worth responding to? One of the worst claims, imo, is that they don’t think Treasury can amend the terms of the SPSPAs to cancel/redeem/etc the seniors because of restrictions on the government’s ability to “compromise a debt”. But the seniors aren’t debt, they’re equity!

    Liked by 1 person

    1. Parrott and Zandi have done a number of papers for the Urban Institute, but this one, in my mind, is unique, in that it substitutes politics for policy in a way that does not do credit to the institution that published it. I intend to make this point to the Urban Institute’s leadership.

      Parrott and Zandi justify their political speculation by writing the following set-up paragraph early in the paper: “Since the early days of the recent Great Recession, conservatives have been highly critical of the role that the GSEs play in the housing finance system. They attribute a significant portion of the blame for the crisis to Fannie and Freddie and bemoan the increased importance of the two institutions in the years since, arguing that they distort the mortgage market and create excessive risk for the taxpayer. To address these concerns, a conservative director of the FHFA will likely take steps to reduce the GSEs’ role in the market.”

      Parrott and Zandi both know that Fannie and Freddie didn’t cause the crisis (Zandi wrote a paper explaining that) and also that they don’t distort the market or create excessive risk for the taxpayer. But they don’t say that, as any actual policy analyst would. Instead, they say that since “conservatives” believe these things (because that’s what advocates for the banks, including Mr. Parrott, keep telling them), and since this is a conservative administration, it therefore follows that the inevitable course of administrative mortgage reform will be to reduce the companies’ “dominance” in the market (and let banks pick up the slack). Through this artifice, the policy merits of everything that follows become irrelevant, and don’t need to be addressed.

      And what follows is a bunch of teeth-gnashing assertions and slanted analysis to justify Parrott and Zandi’s contention that the only possible outcome of “reform” is either what the MBA has been pushing for the last couple of years or something even worse for homebuyers. And if mortgage rates go up 90-100 basis points and the availability of conventional mortgages to lower-income borrowers shrinks to a fraction of what it was pre-crisis, well, there’s unfortunately nothing that can be done about that. It’s complete nonsense.

      I don’t plan to respond to this paper directly—other than the note to Urban Institute leadership mentioned earlier—but I do know some who intend to, and I’ve offered to help with suggestions and comments.

      Liked by 4 people

      1. Tim,

        Thanks for your response. It’s good to hear (judging from your last sentence) that you are not alone in resisting the narratives in that paper.

        Parrott and Zandi’s apparent shift in tactics is just another strange turn in this saga. Their continued insistence on, ahem, “Parrott”ing the false narrative by couching it in terms of “some conservatives think this” while being aware of its falsity should be embarrassing.

        If being conservative was all it took to shrink or gut the GSEs, it would have happened already during Trump’s term. It all sounds like a “No True Scotsman” fallacy to me.

        Liked by 1 person

      2. Tim – What did you think of the discussion by Parrott & Zandi that: “A solution often suggested is to amend the terms of the relevant agreements to reduce the GSEs’ obligations to the taxpayer. However, it is not at all clear that the law allows for such a move. Under 31 U.S. Code § 3711 and 31 CFR 902.2, the government can only “compromise a debt” owed the taxpayer when the debtor cannot pay, the cost of collection is prohibitive, or there is significant doubt as to the government’s liability to prove that the debt is owed. It would not appear that any of these circumstances apply here.”

        Like

        1. I didn’t think much of it, for two reasons. First, Fannie and Freddie’s senior preferred stock is not ” a debt owed to the taxpayer;” it is a confiscatory dividend-paying (not interest-bearing) security Treasury granted to itself after it forced the companies into conservatorship while refusing to tell them (or Fannie, at least) the terms of the “assistance” they would be given. Many commentators have said that Treasury could cancel the senior preferred at any time it wishes, and I agree with that. Which brings me to my second reason. I have lost count of the articles written by Mr. Parrott–some co-authored by Zandi, others not–that contain arguments for why anything other that what he would like to see happen to Fannie and Freddie either isn’t legal, isn’t feasible, runs counter to some obscure rule or precedent, or will end up disadvantaging homebuyers, relative to what he wants to do. I tend to be skeptical about reasons why something can’t be done that are advanced by people who don’t want to do it.

          Like

  22. Any Chance you are in the running to succeed Mel Watt as Director of FHFA ?

    IMF NEWS TODay … Wed May 9, 2018 …

    A former Fannie Mae executive, who worked for the government-sponsored enterprise pre-takeover, is being mentioned as a possible White House pick to succeed Mel Watt as director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency, sources told IMFnews. As more details become available, we’ll let you know…

    Like

    1. If so, I’m being considered without anyone having spoken to me about it. If the rumor is true it’s likely to be someone else, but I don’t know who (nor do I have a good guess).

      Like

      1. As a shareholder of gses, you have my support as president and CEO of Fannie Mae, you have my votes! your experience and knowledge give me the assurance that you are the best executive for any of the gse’s and, of course, for FHFA. In my opinion, you are the best qualified person to find the best role for these companies that, ultimately, is the best for his shareholders and taxpayers.

        Liked by 1 person

        1. One of my ex-Fannie Mae colleagues says that the “former Fannie Mae executive” mentioned in the IMF News item as a possible successor to Mel Watt is Adolfo Marzol, who I know well. He was hired from Chase Mortgage into Fannie’s capital markets group in 1996, then moved to a position in the single-family guaranty business before becoming chief credit officer in 1998. He left Fannie not too long after I did, and shortly thereafter got involved—first as a consultant then as an executive—with Essent Group, a Bermuda-based mortgage insurer and reinsurer. Last May he was named Senior Advisor to Secretary Carson at HUD, where he is now. Adolfo knows the mortgage business, and Fannie and Freddie, well, and in my view would be a better choice as FHFA director than any of the other people whose names have been bruited about for the position.

          Liked by 5 people

  23. Tim

    We all appreciate your work and insight and I apologize to ask but I am curious, are you a shareholder? If so which? Again sorry to ask.

    Like

    1. I own no shares of Freddie Mac, and discussed my holdings of Fannie when I began doing the blog (in February 2016). Enough time has since passed that it’s probably worth repeating: “When I left [Fannie] I held common shares and vested stock options, all obtained as compensation there…I sold no shares, and took shares (not cash) upon exercising stock options, until Fannie Mae completed its earnings restatement in December 2006. From January through June 2007 I sold approximately half of my and my family’s holdings of Fannie Mae common stock. I held the rest when the company went into conservatorship, and in August 2009 sold half those shares and used the proceeds to buy Fannie Mae series N preferred stock (picked because it was the last preferred stock issuance the company did when I was CFO). I have done no transactions in either the common or preferred shares of Fannie Mae since then.” That’s still true, and I’d add that Fannie’s common was trading at around $70 per share when I left, so at today’s prices my holdings of Fannie common and preferred are not a significant percentage of my financial assets (i.e., I’m not doing the blog in the hope of financial gain).

      Liked by 3 people

      1. With respect to the TS, given his 180 from bullish release to sheepish we’ll see, he’s about as in charge of GSE’s as you are Glen. POTUS decides if and when GSE’s come out to play because clearly TS has been given a time out. As to the advice to pick up some more, reckless also given the aforementioned fact. Try handicapping this POTUS. This is purely a political play with a clock fast approaching midnight. This is one step worse than a coin toss because along with the loss probabilities, inactivity is also a leading percentage making a winning toss a two step political parlay. An unbelievably thin margin of success on GSE. (oh, and for good measure, chuckle, the coin holder is paid billions of bloody dollars in perpetuity to just stand there and hold a supposedly worthless coin)

        Taken from “Taken”……..Good luck,

        Like

  24. And who is going to take on the interest rate and prepayment risk of fixed-rate mortgages? That was the key role of the Fannie/Freddie between 1981 and 2008.

    Liked by 1 person

    1. This is an important aspect of the reform debate that the supporters of banks either are unaware of or willfully ignoring. Pre-crisis, Fannie and Freddie supported 30-year fixed rate mortgages in two ways: by issuing fixed-term debt (both callable and non-callable) to investors, and using the proceeds to buy these loans, and by putting low-cost credit guarantees on pools of 30-year mortgages so that capital markets investors could buy them without having to worry about the creditworthiness of the underlying borrowers (which they had no way of assessing).

      When Fannie and Freddie held mortgages in portfolio (and at one point they had a combined $1.65 trillion of them), they took the interest rate and prepayment risk. But they managed that risk with callable debt and derivatives, which they constantly “rebalanced” to keep the durations of their funding closely matched with the estimated durations of their assets. On their MBS, it was capital markets investors who took the prepayment and interest rate risk.

      As I noted in this blog post, Treasury required Fannie and Freddie to greatly shrink their portfolios, for no reason other than the banks had traditionally opposed them (claiming the companies had an “unfair funding advantage” over banks, which is blatantly false—banks’ government-insured consumer deposits, which make up the bulk of their funding, have rates much lower than Fannie and Freddie debt). Today Fannie and Freddie’s portfolios total less than $500 billion, so that’s $1.15 trillion in demand for fixed-rate mortgages that the “reformers” have caused to disappear.

      Now they want to go after the fixed-rate mortgages supplied by capital markets purchasers of Fannie and Freddie-guaranteed MBS, by making the credit guaranty process (unnecessarily) more costly. If successful, this would have two results: first, driving more fixed-rate loans onto the balance sheets of banks—who can earn very wide spreads by funding them with mismatched short-term consumer deposits and purchased funds without incurring any capital penalty, because the Basel III capital requirements don’t penalize banks for taking interest rate risk—and second, making bank-friendly (and consumer-unfriendly) adjustable-rate mortgages relatively more attractive by pushing up guaranty fees, which get added to the cost of fixed-rate loans.

      I am hoping the affordable housing groups and community bankers can drive these points home to members of Congress and Treasury. What the banks want is a much more expensive, more restrictive and riskier mortgage delivery system than we had pre-crisis, for no reason other than to further pad their (already fat) bottom lines.

      Liked by 1 person

      1. “…by making the credit guaranty process (unnecessarily) more costly”

        if there is a treasury mbs guaranty (even assuming that it kicks in after FnF goes insolvent), wouldnt the process become less costly?

        rolg

        Like

        1. What the banks are offering is a package: require Fannie and Freddie to hold an unnecessarily high percentage of capital that will push their guaranty fees up 25 basis points (which benefits the banks, by both driving more loans onto their balance sheets and giving them wider funding spreads on those loans), then add a paid-for government guaranty to cut 10 basis points off that total (which will benefit the banks as well, by lowering the capital risk weight on the F/F MBS they hold from 20 percent to zero). My proposal is a true risk-based capital requirement for F/F, endorsed by Treasury as meeting the government’s high standard of taxpayer protection and backed, if needed, by private catastrophic risk insurance. The latter will deliver a considerably lower all-in mortgage cost to borrowers.

          Liked by 2 people

  25. Tim,

    Thank you for both advocating for good policy, and posting this informative piece in a public forum.

    This is especially important because, as you remind us, the GSEs are “banned from political activities, these banks have been free to distort the record, define the objectives of secondary market reform, and put forth reform proposals that benefit [only] themselves.”

    Your remarks are brief–a necessity given your intended audience. The parsimony that makes this so rhetorically effective, though, necessarily precludes fine detail. Would you mind expanding a bit on this: “the draft Senate bill errs in presenting direct subsidies as an alternative to cross-subsidies, rather than as a complement to them. The two are independent; direct subsidy programs do not in any way lessen the importance of doing as much as possible to support affordable housing through an efficient credit guaranty mechanism.” How, in practice, do direct subsidies and cross-subsidies work?

    Have you had any requests from elected officials or their staffs to elaborate on this or other aspects of this (very tight) piece?

    Like

    1. A direct subsidy is a payment of cash to a targeted borrower type for a specific purpose, such as buying down the mortgage interest rate or assistance in making a down payment or paying closing costs. You might think of these as “hard” subsidies: cash is collected from one source, and paid to another. In contrast, cross-subsidies might be termed “soft” subsidies, where no money changes hands. The way these have worked in the past is that a large number of lower-risk borrowers are charged guaranty fees that are moderately higher than is warranted by the riskiness of their loans (although they don’t know that), so that guaranty fees on a smaller number of higher-risk borrowers can be significantly lower (helping them afford the loan), without the credit guarantor being any worse off. As I mention in the post, both types of subsidies have their roles, although direct subsidies need a significant amount of administrative infrastructure to determine which specific individuals get the subsidies, for what purpose, and how much.

      As for requests from elected officials or their staffs to elaborate on the piece, my policy is not to publicize or comment on those. I find I can be more effective in getting people to agree to meetings (or discussions) if I keep both them and their content confidential.

      Liked by 4 people

  26. Thanks Tim, I always learn something new about housing finance every time I read one of your articles. You have the force of clear and honest reasoning behind you. It’s hard for your opponents to disagree with your factual statements without resorting to obfuscation and rumors.

    Like

  27. Tim,

    A heart felt thank you for your continued work on mortgage finance issues and for being a much needed voice of truth and reason.

    God bless you!

    As an aside, how do you see the common securitization platform fitting in to the future of mortgage finance? Specifically, can you foresee the GSEs (or FHFA) allowing originators use of the CSP for a fee in order to offer their own MBS product?

    Thanks.

    Like

    1. The role the common securitization platform (CSP) will play will depend on when the secondary market of the future is decided upon and implemented. The CSP may well be completed and in operation before that time, in which case I would expect, if Fannie and Freddie are retained in some form, both companies would keep using it. I would be surprised if either of them opens it up to other issuers for a fee, however.

      Liked by 1 person

    1. Certainly. It never hurts for constituents to send articles to their members of Congress. Most such missives don’t make it past the staffers, however, and for that reason there also are people who will be sending the paper (with a title, my name as author, my former affiliation, and date) directly to senators and representatives they know personally.

      Liked by 2 people

  28. Tim,

    What a great piece. Here’s to hoping you and others are finding more than just a few powerful folks, up on The Hill, willing to truly listen and LEARN.

    Thanks again for your amazing efforts!

    Liked by 2 people

  29. What you advocate here sounds great, but what fail-safe covenant would protect this from future politicians meddling with what has proven to work, politics being what it is?

    Like

    1. Having to worry about politicians meddling with a sensible secondary market reform proposal AFTER it has been implemented is what’s known as a “high quality problem.” Let’s get the sensible reform implemented first.

      Liked by 1 person

Leave a reply to Mark Cancel reply